ahorbinski: Tomoe Gozen is so badass she glued her OTW mug to her wrist.  (tomoe gozen would haved loved the OTW)
Bibliographic Data: Mass, Jeffrey P. Yoritomo and the Founding of the First Bakufu: The Origins of Dual Government in Japan. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1999.

Main Argument: "It is the central contention of this book that, thanks to the policies fashioned by Yoritomo in the period before 1200, the traditional order in Japan was extended for another century" (10). Moreover, both the Taira and the Minamoto were not the titans familiar from the literary record; rather, in the case of Kiyomori, his power peaked at the end of his life rather than earlier, and in the case of both, their achievements were not "military" in character. Yoritomo's achievement was "more modest" than Mass first thought when he began writing, though it "is still hugely impressive given the constraints and obstacles that confronted him" (xi). Similarly, the Kamakura bakufu was "an organization that mostly repudiated the use of force, stressing mediation, persuasion, and procedure instead. …In a sense, Kamakura waged a war of words against violence and aggressive behavior throughout the era, as it sought to transmute what it saw as the most threatening forms of juan competition into verbal exchanges in the courtroom" (x). This is not anything like a "warrior government."

Historiographical Engagement: This is a top to bottom rewrite of Mass's first book, which was itself based on his dissertation; he read all the scholarship on medieval Japan in both Japanese and English in the interim.

The bakufu: not all it's cracked up to be )

Critical assessment: This is a very nicely written book, and I think that Mass, who after all basically knew best, is right in most of what he says here. That said, he is not a counter of things (most of the documentation of all of these phenomena is very, very slight), and I also don't endorse the idea that Yoritomo created a "dyarchy." What he did create was a new branch of government that essentially did some duty as military police but, more fundamentally, created an administrative need by inaugurating the jitô and then filled it by managing them. It's quite a neat trick, really, but all the samurai wanted central/courtly preferment and offices, not simply "military honors," the Heike monogatari not withstanding.

Meta notes: Counting things is important.
ahorbinski: Emma Goldman, anarchist (play the red queen's game)
Bibliographic Data: Jenkins, Henry. Convergence Culture: Where Old and New Media Collide. New York: New York University Press, 2006.

Main Argument:
This circulation of media content--across different media systems, competing media economies, and national borders--depends heavily on consumers' active participation. I will argue here against the idea that convergence should be understood primarily as a technological process bringing together multiple media functions within the same devices. Instead, convergence represents a cultural shift as consumers are encouraged to seek out new information and make connections among dispersed media content. This book is about the work--and play--spectators perform in the new media system. (3)

Convergence culture )
Critical assessment: Damn, this book is full of dudes. Also, it's super trippy reading this book now because Jenkins was so right that everything he says in here feels so self-evident as to be axiomatic. There are critiques that could be made--see the entries by Steinberg and by myself in the "Further Reading" section--but by and large Jenkins deserves his position as the prophet of convergence culture, in my opinion. That said, a look at the problems "the Wikipedia" has developed as it has matured shows that new media are not arising in a new environment, but rather are, to some extent, shaped by preexisting structures of oppression and control even as they challenge them. Ah, the post-post-Fordist post-postmodern dilemma.

Further reading: Marc Steinberg, Anime's Media Mix; Alex Leavitt and Andrea Horbinski, "Even a Monkey Can Understand Fan Activism"; Lisa Gitelman, Always Already New; Anne Allison, Millennial Monsters; Andrea Horbinski, "After Henry Jenkins: Transmedia Fandom"

Meta notes: Convergence and divergence are two sides of the same coin.
ahorbinski: My Marxist-feminist dialectic brings all the boys to the yard.  (marxism + feminism --> posthumanism)
Bibliographic Data: Segal, Ethan Isaac. Coins, Trade, and the State: Economic Growth in Early Medieval Japan. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011.

Main Argument: Segal looks at the economic history of early medieval Japan and argues that diffuse political authority in this period enabled three significant changes: one, that the country began to shift definitively from commodity money to metal currency; two, that this initial shift took place in defiance of government control; and three, that "the sweeping changes of this period allowed provincial figures greater economic agency than they experienced in earlier times" (3).

Historiographical Engagement: Delmer Brown, whom Segal disagrees with (Brown saw an unbreakable linkage between political stability and economic growth); Tom Smith and others who believe that monetization did not really pick up until the Edo period (incorrect); Toyoda and Sugiyama, who saw economic growth as a byproduct of political fragmentation

This is not a good book )

Critical assessment: Ethan Segal is no Wally Scheidel, I have to say. He does not actually know enough about money to say some of the things he is saying--for example, he blithely declares that "even when the government attempted to declare some coins to be worth more than others, people appear to have used coins as if they were of uniform value" (59). Only if you take "uniform value" to mean that "bad money had driven out the good in accordance with Gresham's Law, and general debasement meant that most money was not worth much, despite what the court declared" does this sentence make sense. You could also say something like "the Japanese court attempted to enforce a fiduciary currency but was unable to do so, since people tended to use money at its intrinsic value." He also doesn't appear to understand that taxes and rents are not the same thing.

That having been said, although Segal's analysis is often not very sophisticated, I think his conclusions are fundamentally correct. I also think that there is a better book out there waiting to be written on Japanese currency and monetization than this one.

Further reading: William Wayne Farris, Japan's Medieval Population; Janet Goodwin, Alms and Vagabonds

Meta notes: It might be useful to understand how money works before writing a book about it, IJS.
ahorbinski: a bridge in the fog (bridge to anywhere)
Bibliographic Data: Moretti, Franco. Graphs, Maps, Trees: Abstract Models for a Literary History. London: Verso, 2005.

Main Argument: Moretti is arguing for a literary history that is based on "distance reading," "where distance is however not an obstacle, but a specific form of knowledge" (1), and in which one moves from texts to models so as to get a sense of the interconnectedness of general elements. Rather than high theory, he draws on the natural sciences as an inspiration.

Graphs, Maps, Trees )

Critical assessment: Give me a lever long enough and I'll move the world; the lever need not be particularly long if it is a book. It's sort of hard to critique a revolutionary text, and so it is with this one. One can only take what it says to heart in whichever way one pleases.

Further reading: Anne Burdic et al., Digital_Humanities; Stephen Ramsay, Reading Machines; Patrik Svensson, "The Landscape of Digital Humanities"

Meta notes: Don't miss the forest for the trees.
ahorbinski: an imperial stormtrooper with the word "justic3" (imperial justice)
Bibliographic Data: Rosenstein, Nathan. “War, State Formation, and the Evolution of Military Institutions in Ancient China and Rome.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 24-51. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

War & State Formation )

Bibliographic Data: Scheidel, Walter. “From the ‘Great Convergence’ to the ‘First Great Divergence’: Roman and Qin-Han State Formation and Its Aftermath.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 11-23. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Convergence & Divergence )

Bibliographic Data:
Turner, Karen. “Law and Punishment in the Formation of Empire.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 52-82. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Law and Punishment )

Bibliographic Data: Bang, Peter Fibiger. “Commanding and Consuming the World: Empire, Tribute, and Trade in Roman and Chinese History.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 100-120. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Tribute & Trade )

Bibliographic Data: Dettenhofer, Maria H. “Eunuchs, Women, and Imperial Courts.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 83-99. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Main Argument: Women and men of humble background surrounded the emperor in both Rome and China; in Rome these men were first freedmen and then equestrians, and then in late antiquity, eunuchs, while in China they were eunuchs throughout the period. Moreover, women and eunuchs were natural allies--or bitter rivals--in the struggle for political influence, made easier by their service to the emperor in intimate matters. Eunuchs came to prominence at the Roman court after the crisis of the 3rdC isolated the emperor from elites both physically and through ritual. Moreover, "eunuchs were unpopular in both societies. They represented a despised group that was only able to exist inside the court and under the emperor's protection" (98).

Bibliographic Data: Lewis, Mark Edward. “Gift Circulation and Charity in the Han and Roman Empires.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires,121-136. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Gifts & Charity )

Bibliographic Data: Scheidel, Walter. “The Monetary Systems of the Han and Roman Empires.” In Walter Scheidel, ed., Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires, 137-207. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.

Cash Money )

Critical assessment:
These chapters are for the most part very good, although I have several specific complaints. First, the Detenhoffer article is an intellectual fluff piece made actively bad by its completely thoughtless throwing around of terms such as "bisexual" in a totally non-contextualized and untheorized way. I also disagree with Karen Turner's implicit argument that Roman law in the empire or in its successor states was somehow more humane than imperial Chinese law; the fact that England eventually developed trial by jury is totally irrelevant to the actual question. I also think Wally Scheidel's inability to recognize the Second Great Convergence beginning in the 19thC is problematic, since the whole point of--many things, including this book--is that we are now in a unified world system, for better and for worse. Finally, while I take Bang's point, it's a little weird to me to just subsume trade under tribute as the same thing.

Meta notes: Two houses, both alike in equal dignity…
ahorbinski: text says "in capitalist America, bank robs you" (we are the 99%)
Bibliographic Data: Jongman, Willem M. “The Early Roman Empire: Consumption.” In The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, ed. Walter Scheidel, Ian Morris, and Richard Saller, 592-618. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Consumption )

Bibliographic Data: Kehoe, Dennis P. “The Early Roman Empire: Production.” In The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, ed. Walter Scheidel, Ian Morris, and Richard Saller, 543-69. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Production )

Bibliographic Data: Lo Cascio, Elio. “The Early Roman Empire: The State and the Economy.” In The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, ed. Walter Scheidel, Ian Morris, and Richard Saller, 619-50. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.

The State and the Economy )

Bibliographic Data: Morley, Neville. “The Early Roman Empire: Distribution.” In The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, ed. Walter Scheidel, Ian Morris, and Richard Saller, 570-91. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Distribution )

Critical assessment: I am highly suspicious of Kehoe's overall argument, but the rest of these articles seem pretty solid. (See future posts for caveats about the generally optimistic tone of being able to know the Roman imperial economy in toto, however.)

Meta notes: It's the economy, stupid.
ahorbinski: My Marxist-feminist dialectic brings all the boys to the yard.  (marxism + feminism --> posthumanism)
Bibliographic Data: Stalin, Josef V. The Foundations of Leninism. Beijing: Foreign Language Press, 1965.

Main Argument: "Leninism is Marxism of the era of imperialism and proletarian revolution" (2). Moreover, the "exceptionally militant and exceptionally revolutionary character of Leninism" is attributable to two factors: 1) "that Leninism emerged from the proletarian revolution"; and 2) "that it grew and became strong in clashes with the opportunism of the Second International, the fight against which was and remains an essential preliminary condition for a successful fight against capitalism" (3).

Imperialism is the highest form of capitalism )

Critical assessment: Reading this is kind of like looking through a funhouse mirror at the history of the 20thC. I could, without too much effort, transpose a lot of what Stalin is saying here into arguments that Ken Pomeranz and many others have made--the refreshing thing, in many ways, is how much Lenin and Stalin got right, even as they were, in so many other horrible and tragic ways, utterly utterly wrong. NB, however, that Mao is not the person who introduced the peasantry as a revolutionary reserve into Marxism; that is Lenin, which Stalin reinforces here.

Meta notes: Workers of the world, unite! You have nothing to lose but your chains.
ahorbinski: kanji (kanji)
Bibliographic Data: Lurie, David B. Realms of Literacy: Early Japan and the History of Writing. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center, 2011.

Main Argument: "This study is, first and foremost, a history of writing in early Japan, but as the subtitle suggests, it also aims to rethink the wider history of writing in general" (2). "By insisting on the multilingual nature of the 'Chinese' script, which crossed and complicated language boundaries in real time as well as over long periods, this book presents an unfamiliar picture of writing in Japan and the wider region around it. Attention to the history of reading, and to the varied ways in which writing has been linked to language, shows that there are overlaps and intersections between uses of writing that have traditionally been separated into categories like foreign and native or Sinitic and vernacular" (vii).

Historiographical Engagement: History and theory of writing and history of writing in Japan.

Introduction: Argument, Sources, Examples "Deeper understanding of early Japanese inscription will transform comparative discussions of literacy and reading practices, and remake our sense of the wider patterns of the world history of writing systems" (1). Lurie discusses the difficulty of defining what it means to say that writing ever "begins," and he argues that the explosion of writing in Japan in the 7thC, although obviously connected to accelerating state formation, is in fact quite varied: "Rather than a uniform transition from orality to literacy, these materials reveal different modes of writing appearing around the same time and coexisting in a variety of configurations. …different social groups are simultaneously using texts in radically different ways" (4). Lurie also criticizes the implicit "alphabetism" of scholars of writing, who, he says, "should do more to avoid teleological assumptions about progress towards photography, assumptions that are often implicitly linked to claims about the (Greek) alphabet as a guarantor of cultural superiority" (5). He argues, moreover, that the process of kundoku, "reading by gloss," "dominated all modes of literacy in early Japan, from at least the mid-seventh century on. This means that we cannot describe texts arranged in accordance with Chinese vocabulary and syntax as being written 'in Chinese' (no matter what their origins, a conclusion that has profound implications for Japanese cultural history, which has been framed by a linguistic opposition between Chinese and Japanese" (ibid). Moreover, considering Chinese writing as the "East Asian writing system," for example, and early Japanese reading and writing systems, "threatens widely held assumptions about the place of phonographic adaptation in the world history of writing" (6). The history of these questions assumptions about the "historical development of inscription and also more technical discussions of the relations between script and language" (7).

Literacies and writing systems )

But the broader point remains: in terms of their functioning in society and development over time, it is difficult to find deep, qualitative differences across various systems of writing. As visually and structurally distinctive as many features of Japanese writing are, it seems that they neither produced, nor were determined by, sharp cultural or social differences. In a sense, this means that although writing in Japan (and to some extent, writing in general) does not work quite in the way that has often been assumed, that difference itself turns out to be less consequential than might be expected. Many scholars and theorists have taken an integral developmental logic of writing to be a key to the history of humanity; but such a logic may not even be a key to the history of writing itself. … Writing's connection to natural language and its catalytic effect on so many other historical developments make it seem to be a special case. Perhaps it is. But in its multifariousness and malleability, it is as resistant as any other human practice to monocausal, deterministic explanation. (363-64)

Critical assessment: This is a really excellent book that I am sure these notes have not fully captured. I need to think about everything that Lurie says some more, but I think a lot of his arguments could be profitably applied to technologies other than writing in Japan, such as states. And of course, there's the arguments about the history of writing, which seem to me, from what I know about it (I did some research on the development of the Greek alphabet for a while once, so I know some things; in fact, when it comes to the Greek alphabet, I actually know many things), to be right on the money.

Further reading: Tom Lamarre, Uncovering Heian Japan; Tomiko Yoda, Gender and National Literature

Meta notes: Techno-determinism is as much at work in how we think about writing as it is in how we think about computers.
ahorbinski: kanji (kanji)
Bibliographic Data: Akamatsu Toshihide and Philp Yampolsky. “Muromachi Zen and the Gozan System.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 313-30.

Argument, Sources, Examples The Gozan system, adopted from China, by which the Ashikaga shogunate managed and subordinated Rinzai Zen, quickly became "almost entirely bureaucratic in nature," and at the same time, "enthusiasm for Zen study waned" (319), possibly because Zen began to incorporate elements of an esoteric tradition and because in the 14thC (i.e. the Yuan dynasty) direct connections with China waned. Provincial (i.e. Soto) Zen gained in popularity after the Ônin War, "but it too changed radically in style. It was now a simplified and formalized teaching with numerous extraneous elements derived from other forms of Buddhism, both esoteric and Pure Land" (ibid). The leashing of Zen doubtless served the bakufu's interests, as did the generally tight links between the Zen temples and the bakufu itself.

Bibliographic Data: Itō Teiji with Paul Novograd. “The Development of Shoin-Style Architecture.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 227-40.

Argument, Sources, Examples The development of what later came to be called the "shoin style" of architecture in the Muromachi age is a modification of the Heian and Kamakura style of palace architecture "in adaptation to new social and cultural practices" (228). "The crumbling of the old rigidly stratified society, the spread of freer, more casual relations between members of the military aristocracy or between upper and lower levels of society, as well as the emergence of new cultural pursuits such as the tea ceremony, renga composing parties, and the rage for displaying Chinese art and artifacts led to new forms of architecture to accommodate these changing patterns in social behavior and cultural life" (227). It is only after the consolidation of the style as such in the Momoyama period that the last of the palace style features dropped out of shoin style; all Muromachi shoin style structures retain vestigial palace style elements, as architecturally speaking the Muromachi period was a transitional phase. Shoin elements include such stereotypically "Japanese" practices as tatami mats covering the floors, no distinction between central chamber and outer veranda, and the decorative or writing alcoves with shelves for display, as well as sliding door and wall panels.

Bibliographic Data: Kawai Masaharu with Kenneth A. Grossberg. “Shogun and Shugo: The Provincial Aspects of Muromachi Politics.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 65-86.

Shogun and shugo )

Bibliographic Data: Miyagawa Mitsuru with Cornelius J. Kiley. “From Shōen to Chigyō: Proprietary Lordship and the Structure of Power.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 89-106.

Shoen to chigyo )

Bibliographic Data: Nagahara Keiji with Kozo Yamamura. “Village Communities and Daimyo Power.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 107-24.

Villages and daimyo )

Bibliographic Data: Satō Shin’ichi with John W. Hall. “The Ashikaga Shogun and the Muromachi Bakufu Administration.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 45-52.

Shogun and bakufu )
Bibliographic Data: Toyoda Takeshi and Sugiyama Hiroshi with V. Dixon Morris. “The Growth of Commerce and the Trades.” In Japan in the Muromachi Age, ed. John W. Hall and Toyoda Takeshi. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2001 [1977]: 129-44.

Commerce and trades )

Critical assessment: This book is a wealth of interesting, critical, and relevant material; I've only covered only about half of it. Even the stuff that isn't ground-breaking is interesting. Medieval Japan was far more interesting than those who talked about "the Dark Ages" would think.

Further reading: Tonomura, Community and Commerce in Late Medieval Japan; Segal, Coins, Trade, and the State; Keirstead, The Geography of Power in Medieval Japan; Mass, Antiquity and Anachronism in Japanese History

Meta notes: Everyone had more fun in the medieval period.
ahorbinski: Tomoe Gozen is so badass she glued her OTW mug to her wrist.  (tomoe gozen would haved loved the OTW)
Bibliographic Data: Sato, Elizabeth. “The Early Development of the Shōen.” In Medieval Japan: Essays in Institutional History, ed. John W. Hall and Jeffrey P. Mass. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1988 [1974]: 91-108.

Main Argument: Shôen emerged beginning in the 8thC CE; most early shôen, however, came from the ritsuryo category of "land available for reclamation," in which the reclaimer's nominal right of proprietorship for two to three generations was granted in perpetuity. Although they emerged at the same time as the ritsuryo government began to revert to patrimonial power and extra-legal customs began to supersede the state's laws on paper, shôen were not initially part of this process. Those early shôen that did become later shôen did so through the commendatory process, in which original proprietors commended the estate to a central proprietor so as to avoid encroachment from the state's provincial officers.

Argument, Sources, Examples Two factors are crucial in analysis of the shôen: when they were developed and the land itself. "Although in later times rights to income from land became more important than the land itself, in the early stages of shôen development, the reverse was true: in order to produce income, land first had to be developed" (95). The early shôen, moreover, was "a relatively compact unity that could be handled by a simple administrative structure" (96). Finally, "tax immunity, then, was not necessarily a defining characteristic of the early shôen, although most entities that were called such by their holders eventually received at least a partial exemption from taxation. Those that did not simply failed to survive" (ibid). The point, however, is that "lands were granted for reclamation before they received tax immunity" (ibid). Beginning in the early ninth century, however, as landholding rights on the ground changed, shôen emerged as an institution for proprietary control over the land, which became complete when an estate's proprietor acquired not only tax immunity but also immunity to entry by government officials. The shôen survived as an institutional form because it offered a great deal of flexibility--different rights and privileges could be granted to different members at all levels (shômin-shôke-ryôke-honke) based on their particular circumstances, and "it was possible for changes to take place at one level without substantially affecting the other levels" (107). Moreover, "it was possible for the income of the shôen to be widely distributed. Shiki [income rights] could change hands through sale, inheritance, or donation without disturbing the function of the shôen as an economic unit" (ibid). This flexibility was reciprocal, in that cultivators and proprietors could change without disturbing the others without threat to the shôen itself: "as an economic system, the shôen offered advantages to all of its constituents" (108).

Bibliographic Data: Kiley, Cornelius J. “Provincial Administration and Land Tenure in Early Japan.” In The Cambridge History of Japan vol. 2, ed. Donald H. Shively and William H. McCullough. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999: 236-340.

Main Argument: Kiley traces the transition from, essentially, the ritsuryô to the shôen system from the 9th to 12thC. This transition can be roughly divided into three phases; in the first, in the 9th and 10thC, rural notables of a type that Kiley calls "petty gentry" inserted themselves into the ritsuryô state as, essentially, tax farmers, acting as intermediaries between official tax collectors and the tax renderers themselves [though communal rendering of tax goods was not new; see Yoshie]. In the second, in the 11thC, "provincial governments were, without permission from the capital, beginning to license certain holdings as the specially chartered possessions of their 'cultivators,' endowed with specific tax preferences" (243). In the third, in the 12thC, what are known as "mature shôen" began to emerge, partly through the administration of Shirakawa, who as retired emperor promulgated many edicts ostensibly registering and curbing shôen but in actuality mostly confirming their rights of immunities in toto (since at this point the imperial house too was trying to get in on the tax-immunity game).

Argument, Sources, Examples One important point to note in this story is the tenacious survival of the office of the provincial governments; although governors themselves did not much travel to their bailiwicks after the high Heian period, but instead entrusted the administration of their provinces to custodians known as zuryô, "the provincial governments themselves proved to be among the most durable of ritsuryô institutions, probably because from the beginning they served to integrate the interests of local elites, capital officials, and court nobility" (253). The fact that more and more authority was entrusted to resident officials meant that they assumed more and more autonomy from the capital, strengthening provincial governments in general. In the second phase, "a domainal landholding system evolved and, by about the year 1100, the subject populace had also been reorganized, bringing whole communities of cultivators under the patrimonial control of domainal lords or proprietary officeholders" (253). Through the process of commendation which led to the consolidation of mature shôen as three-level institutions--original local proprietors (geshi or azukaridokoro), the lord (ryôshu or ryôke) and the principal in the capital (honjo)--both territory and people were divided between the provincial domains and shôen in the third phase. It is important to note, however, that through this entire period and into the medieval era, what was actually important was not the land itself but rather shiki ("commission") rights to income from the land--whether in kind or in labor, both of which were tax goods by the third phase of this progression. However, the emergence and enforcement of shiki, by which de facto title to land was effectively consolidated, was also related to what Kiley calls "the rapid militarization of the 11thC rural elite" (245). These developments spelled the end of the zuryô system, which Kiley argues "had within it the seeds of its own destruction; increasingly, the newly consolidated (and militarized) local elites could deal with the capital nobility directly, without the governor as intermediary" (248). Remember that these militarized rural elites were the people who fought in, and in some senses caused, the Gempei Wars. But also, shôen were not the sole form through which land was held at this point: there still remained land that was designated kokugaryô in each province at this point, held by the state and administered by those working in the provincial government offices.

Critical assessment: I've had complaints about Kiley in other contexts, but this chapter seems very solid; it also fits well with what we know about the early shôen from Sato, whose analysis likewise seems quite solid. I don't envy either of these scholars combing through documents, or the scholarship, about the shôen; they are famously complicated and famously somewhat boring once you descend from any but the most general level.

Further reading: Nagahara, "Landownership under the Shôen-Kokugaryô System"; Mass, "Jitô Land Possession in the 13thC"; Kawai, "Shogun and Shugo"; Miyagawa, "From Shôen to Chigyô"; Chris Wickham, Framing the Early Middle Ages

Meta notes: It is totally correct to call medieval Japan "feudal." The problem is that most people don't understand what that means.

Profile

ahorbinski: shelves stuffed with books (Default)
Andrea J. Horbinski

August 2017

S M T W T F S
   1 2345
6789101112
13141516171819
20212223242526
2728293031  

Syndicate

RSS Atom

Style Credit

Expand Cut Tags

No cut tags